FAIRNESS CONSIDERATIONS IN THE LIVE MUSIC INDUSTRY

By Hendrik Sonnabend

decapitated_live__klub_studio_krakow_poland_june_5th_2012

Traditional economic thinking presumes artists in the live music business to act like a monopolist who adjusts the ticket price to variations in demand whenever it is possible. This contribution provides strong evidence indicating that they do not. I argue that this behavior can best be explained with fairness expectations on the part of concert attendees.

“Barbra Streisand has canceled a Rome concert that would have launched her European tour […]. Earlier this month, two consumer activist groups in Italy complained that tour promoters were charging exorbitant prices for tickets to the Rome show. They urged Rome’s city government and Italy’s Olympic Committee to deny permission for the singer to use the stadium. They said prices ranging from 150 euros (101 pounds) to 900 euros (610 pounds) were “absurd and shameful.” By comparison, the best seats at Milan’s La Scala opera house run about 200 euros (135 pounds).”   (Reuters, May 26, 2007)

This anecdote gives two main insights:

  1. Unlike the textbook consumer, people can react emotionally to pricing tactics.
  2. People seem to have some kind of reference point to judge prices (here: the price for the opera house’s best seats).

The theory to explain this behavior is called behavioral pricing. Basically, it links psychological aspects to consumer price acceptance. In a pioneering study by Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (1986), respondents were asked to judge price patterns. The authors found that there are norms of fairness linked with reference transactions, like a reference profit for sellers and a reference price for buyers. Their “Dual Entitlement” principle declares that it is perceived as unfair to exploit increased market power (like charging a higher price for snow shovels after a blizzard), while an adjustment to increased costs is considered as fair. Finally, there seems to be a willingness to punish unfair pricing behavior in terms of boycotts or protests.

This contribution addresses the existence of fair pricing in the field of live music using data from the German club concert industry. The concert industry is an appealing candidate since artists typically face strong incentives for optimal pricing decisions (to put it pointedly: after the so called “MP3 crisis”, recorded music serves to promote live music, not the other way round) and prices are transparent and easy to observe. Moreover, “fans” differ from the standard consumer in that they attach a specific value to music and feel an emotional connection to the artist, which also bears the risk of disappointment and rejection. Besides methodological advantages, the restriction to clubs as a venue for live music ensures a shorter distance between the musicians and their fans, literally and from a psychological point of view, compared to large venues such as sports stadiums or arenas.

Regarding the market structure, the diversity of the music scene and the existence of market frictions like travel costs for the concert attendees leave pricing power to the suppliers of live music. Consequently, classic economic theory would predict price discrimination whenever it is possible, meaning different prices for different venues of a tour depending on the expected demand and the venue size. However, if one follows the “Dual Entitlement” approach, things are not that clear. Applied to the live music market, this theory indicates that price dispersion exists in the concert industry, but might be limited to an adaption to differences in costs. This is because if concert-goers have a concept of a fair price, e.g. the price associated with zero economic profits, a price above the fair price triggers anger and rejection. Hence, a second dampening effect on demand besides the ordinary price effect occurs. Now if artists anticipate the disproportionate negative impact on demand, they have an incentive not to exploit their market power and handle price adjustments with care. Ticket prices keep rigid even for events with a higher expected demand.

I tested the two opposing hypotheses with data from the German club concert industry covering 1,490 events performed by 226 artists in 549 venues (clubs), located in 234 different German cities and some venues in neighboring countries. Summary statistics of prices and tour length can be found in the table below.

Table A: Concert Price and Tour Length

Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum
Concert price [€] 22.83 5.44 11 43.50
Tour length (number of concerts) 6.59 4.85 2 26

.

The main findings are:

  1. A uniform price over a whole tour is set by only a very small fraction of artists within the whole sample, which means that price dispersion is the dominant pricing strategy in the club concert industry.
  2. Live music performances take place significantly more often on the weekend (see Table B), so it seems to be a strategic decision to schedule a concert on a Friday or Saturday as the typical “party nights”. As evening events are much more enjoyable when followed by a day off, one would expect a higher demand for these concerts.
  3. Econometric analysis, however, reveals that artists do not charge higher prices for weekend concerts, except for large price deviations.
  4. Ticket prices are positively correlated with a city’s number of inhabitants, which can be explained with higher costs in a metropolis, such as rents or wages for local employees.

Table B: Occurrence of Concerts

Weekday

Share Total

Friday or Saturday

47.05 670

(Expected)

(28.57)

(407)

Rest of the week 52.95

754

(Expected) (71.43)

(1017)

.

To sum up, data shows that price dispersion exists in the concert industry, but is restricted to an adaption to differences in costs. This finding is difficult to explain within a standard profit maximization framework, but is consistent with the idea of fairness constraints as proposed by Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (1986). Artists refrain to exploit the higher expected demand for weekend concerts because they do not want to upset and disappoint their fans. Furthermore, there is reason to believe that this mechanism associated with fairness expectations can be transferred to other markets, especially when the traded good establishes a connection between producer and consumer beyond an ordinary buyer-seller relationship.

.

This text is based on:

Sonnabend, H. (2016). Fairness constraints on profit-seeking: evidence from the German club concert industry.  Journal of Cultural Economics, 40(4),   529-545.

Reference:

Kahneman, D., J. L. Knetsch, and R. Thaler (1986): “Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market,” The American Economic Review, 76(4), 728–741.

Author information:

Hendrik Sonnabend is a postdoctoral researcher in the Department of Economics at the University of Hagen, Germany.

Image source:

Photograph by Grzegorz Furlaga. From Wikimedia Commons.

Leave a Reply

Blog at WordPress.com.

Up ↑

%d bloggers like this: